Famine in Ireland

by Chris Bertram on December 17, 2003

I’ve just reached Amartya Sen’s chapter “Famines and Other Crises” in “Development as Freedom”:http://www.amazon.com/exec/obidos/ASIN/0385720270/junius-20 . He has some discussion of the great famines that depopulated Ireland from 1845 onwards. The potato blight had destroyed the crop but the Irish peasantry lacked the resources to buy alternative foodstuffs which continued to be exported:

bq. ship after ship — laden with wheat, oats, cattle, pigs, eggs and butter — sailed down the Shannon bound for well-fed England from famine-stricken Ireland. (p.172)

Sen argues that cultural alienation (or even hostility) meant that

bq. very little help was provided by the government of the United Kingdom to alleviate to destitution and starvation of the Irish through the period of the famine. (p. 173)

Interesting, because “Natalie Solent”:http://nataliesolent.blogspot.com , who has been writing about famines recently links to “an essay in the National Review Online”:http://www.nationalreview.com/derbyshire/derbyshire072602.asp by the awful John Derbyshire on the subject. Derbyshire asks why the

bq. British government did not organize adequate relief, or prevent the export of foodstuffs from Ireland while Irish people were starving.

and answers

bq. it was not within the nature, philosophy or resources of Anglo-Saxon governments to do such things in the 1840s.

Contrast Sen, who knows the facts:

bq. … by the 1840s, when the Irish famine occurred, an extensive system of poverty relief was fairly well established in Britain, as far as Britain itself was concerned. England too had its share of the poor, and even the life of the employed English worker was far from prosperous …. But there was still some political commitment to prevent open starvation withing England. A similar commitment did not apply to the Empire — not even to Ireland. Even the Poor Laws gave the English destitute substantially more rights than the Irish destitute got from the more anemic Poor Laws that were instituted for Ireland.

So contra Derbyshire, who is probably just making it up as he goes along (but then gets quoted and circulated around the network of misinformation that is the blogosphere) it was “in the nature” of Anglo-Saxon governments, even in the 1840s to do “such things”. Just not for the Irish or the Indians.

Sen also provides us with this striking portrait of Edward Trevelyan

bq. the head of the Treasury during the Irish famines, who saw not much wrong with British economic policy in Ireland (of which he was in charge), point[ing] to Irish habits as part of the explanation of the famines. Chief among the habitual failures was the tendency of the Irish poor to eat only potatoes, which made them dependent on one crop. Indeed, Trevelyan’s view of the causation of the Irish famines permitted him to link them with his analysis of Irish cooking: “There is scarcely a woman of the peasant class in the West of Ireland whose culinary art exceeds the boiling of a potato.” The remark is of interest not just because it is rather rare for an Englishman to find a suitable occasion for making international criticism of culinary art. Rather, the pointing of an accusing finger at the meagreness of the diet of the Irish poor well illustrates the tendency to blame the victim. The victims, in his view, had helped themselves to a disaster, despite the best efforts of the administration in London to prevent it. (p. 175)

Blaming the victim, bad choices, poor diet — I’ve heard those explanations before somewhere. And cultural alienation from those suffering from acute poverty? _Plus ca change, plus c’est la meme chose_ .

{ 61 comments }

1

Ted Barlow 12.17.03 at 7:07 pm

“Blaming the victim, bad choices, poor diet — I’ve heard those explanations before somewhere.”

Heh, heh, heh.

2

Gareth 12.17.03 at 7:12 pm

To return to a topical issue, isn’t this why imperialism is worse than (most) dictatorships? The English ruling class *had* to care about whether the English poor were starving, but it didn’t have to care about whether the Irish were.

True, imperialism is no worse in this respect (and maybe better) than rule by a neighbouring and hostile ethnic group.

What does Niall Ferguson have to say on the subject?

3

Kieran Healy 12.17.03 at 7:29 pm

There was a lot of controversy at the time about relief in Ireland. Some of the more clear-minded commentators (many working for the state) were well aware of what could have been done if the Government chose to act. The Irish Poor Law Commissioner resigned in protest at the derisory level of relief provided by the Crown. John Mitchel’s contemporary summary has borne up pretty well:

bq. I have called it an artificial famine: that is to say, it was a famine which desolated a rich and fertile island, that produced every year abundance and superabundance to sustain all her people and many more. The English, indeed, call the famine a “dispensation of Providence;” and ascribe it entirely to the blight on potatoes. But potatoes failed in like manner all over Europe; yet there was no famine save in Ireland. The British account of the matter, then, is first, a fraud – second, a blasphemy. The Almighty, indeed, sent the potato blight, but the English created the famine.

Meanwhile, in the expected if perhaps not the best traditions of his discpline, the economist Nassau Senior thought that the famine “would not kill more than one million people, and that would scarcely be enough to do any good.”

4

Nicholas Weininger 12.17.03 at 8:27 pm

Of course, one can be against imperialism and imperial double standards– and can be sympathetic to the plight of poor people– without being in favor of welfarism.

5

Carlos 12.17.03 at 8:47 pm

“Of course, one can be against imperialism and imperial double standards— and can be sympathetic to the plight of poor people— without being in favor of welfarism.”

A modest proposal: Britain should have reduced its own poverty relief to Irish levels, thus reducing both the imperial double standard and welfarism. Win-win!

6

--kip 12.17.03 at 8:48 pm

Sympathy means fuck-all if you tie your hands behind your back and refuse to do something about the problem with whatever tools are at your disposal.

7

dsquared 12.17.03 at 8:57 pm

Of course, one can be against imperialism and imperial double standards— and can be sympathetic to the plight of poor people— without being in favor of welfarism.

True, although one does risk the charge of hypocrisy …

8

Micha Ghertner 12.17.03 at 9:44 pm

It’s now hypocrisy to be sympathetic to the plight of poor people while opposing welfare statism? What an interesting world we live in…

9

KevinNYC 12.17.03 at 9:52 pm

Is feeding a starving population “welfarism?”

10

Ryan 12.17.03 at 10:20 pm

A government with policies explicitly denying people the right to own land based on their religion and ethnicity…. protectionist agricultural price controls…. massive taxation to fund make-work programs paying below-market wages…. deflation caused by restrictive new credit policies….

I hope Sen (or Bertram) is not attempting to imply that the Irish of the 1840’s lived in a free-market system IN ANY WAY comparable to that of the modern United States. To do so would be horribly offensive to the multitudes of Irish killed by Britain’s genocidal policies.

I also hope that believers in free markets will not take the bait and attempt to defend British policies toward Ireland.

11

roger 12.17.03 at 10:23 pm

There is a name for the kinds of famine that were endemic to the British empire in the nineteenth century — from Ireland to the series of famines that killed, conservatively, ten to fifteen million in India from 1876 to 1910: terror famines. Conquest’s term, which implies that famine can be a state policy, has so far been applied solely to the Soviet Union, and Stalin’s decision to use famine to re-organize economic relations in the Ukrainian and Russian countryside. But Stalin was merely following in the path of the Britich governments of 1848 and the policy of Viceroys like Lord Lytton in India in 1876-8. Mike Davis’s Victorian Holocaust is a great source of information about this — although Davis rather misses his analogy, comparing British policy to the Nazis when the Nazis were using starvation solely as a genocidal tool. Like Stalin, the Brits simply wanted to impose a new form on an agricultural society, and thought it was worth a couple million worthless peasant lives to do so. Captitalism, like Socialism, begins with some form of central planning, contra Hayek.

Great topic.

12

roger 12.17.03 at 10:23 pm

There is a name for the kinds of famine that were endemic to the British empire in the nineteenth century — from Ireland to the series of famines that killed, conservatively, ten to fifteen million in India from 1876 to 1910: terror famines. Conquest’s term, which implies that famine can be a state policy, has so far been applied solely to the Soviet Union, and Stalin’s decision to use famine to re-organize economic relations in the Ukrainian and Russian countryside. But Stalin was merely following in the path of the Britich governments of 1848 and the policy of Viceroys like Lord Lytton in India in 1876-8. Mike Davis’s Victorian Holocaust is a great source of information about this — although Davis rather misses his analogy, comparing British policy to the Nazis when the Nazis were using starvation solely as a genocidal tool. Like Stalin, the Brits simply wanted to impose a new form on an agricultural society, and thought it was worth a couple million worthless peasant lives to do so. Capitalism, like Socialism, begins with some form of central planning, contra Hayek.

Great topic.

13

james 12.17.03 at 11:27 pm

I don’t know enough about the famine to comment confidently, but here’s a relevent poem:

The Famine Road (by Eavan Boland)

Idle as trout in light Colonel Jones
these Irish, give them no coins at all; their bones
need toil, their characters no less. Trevelyan’s
seal blooded the deal table. The Relief
Committee deliberated: Might it be safe,
Colonel, to give them roads, roads to force
From nowhere, going nowhere of course?

one out of every ten and then
another third of those again
women ñ in a case like yours.

Sick, directionless they worked. Fork, stick
were iron years away; after all could
they not blood their knuckles on rock, suck
April hailstones for water and for food?
Why for that, cunning as housewives, each eyed ñ
as if at a corner butcher ñ the other’s buttock.

anything may have caused it, spores
a childhood accident; one sees
day after day these mysteries.

Dusk: they will work tomorrow without him.
They know it and walk clear. He has become
a typhoid pariah, his blood tainted, although
he shares it with some there. No more than snow
attends its own flakes where they settle
and melt, will they pray by his death rattle.

You never will, never you know
but take it well woman, grow
your garden, keep house, good-bye.

It has gone better than we expected, Lord
Trevelyan, sedition, idleness, cured
in one. From parish to parish, field to field;
the wretches work till they are quite worn,
then fester by their work. We march the corn
to the ships in peace. This Tuesday I saw bones
out of my carriage window. Your servant Jones.

Barren, never to know the load
of his child in you, what is your body
now if not a famine road?

14

jw mason 12.18.03 at 12:27 am

has so far been applied solely to the Soviet Union

Actually Sen comapres the Ukraine and Bengal famines himself, in the very book under discussion.

15

John Isbell 12.18.03 at 12:50 am

Great post, good thread. These posts have prompted me to get the Sen book for my brother for Christmas. Growing up in England, 1973-1993, you heard very little about Ireland pre-1916, and not much after that beyond a working sense of Northern Irish politics since the Troubles. A black mark on English history teaching as I saw it. You learned more about India, still your basic imperialist view.

16

Zizka 12.18.03 at 2:42 am

Paul Dunne of the Shamrockshire Eagle found a contemporary piece by a Randian (apparently of Irish nationality, believe it or not)which blames the potato-eating Irish for their own fate. Of course any good freemarketer must praise famines, which are a good way of reducing the costly burden of excess labor capacity. You only want so much of that reserve army. Derbyshire didn’t have the guts to say so, though.

http://internetcommentator.blogspot.com/2003_11_23_internetcommentator_archive.html#106993587653753080

http://shamrockshire.yi.org/

17

Zizka 12.18.03 at 3:02 am

18

dsquared 12.18.03 at 7:10 am

I hope Sen (or Bertram) is not attempting to imply that the Irish of the 1840’s lived in a free-market system IN ANY WAY comparable to that of the modern United States

I note in passing that the UK of the 1840s had a lower ratio of tax to GDP, lower tariffs and far fewer regulations than the United States. It was much, much more comparable to a laissez-faire state than the modern USA.

19

Chris Bertram 12.18.03 at 8:27 am

_I hope Sen (or Bertram) is not attempting to imply that the Irish of the 1840’s lived in a free-market system IN ANY WAY comparable to that of the modern United States_

Since I didn’t mention the US in my post and Sen is not discussing the US in the passages mentioned, I’m inclined to diagnose this comment as an acute case of Carly Simon syndrome.

If you do want a modern US comparison, though, one springs readily to mind. A lot of people dying, those in power either themselves hostile or indifferent or beholden to a constituence hostile and indifferent to the people dying. A strong tendency to blame the victims. Public action that could have been undertaken but wasn’t because of that indifference and hostility….

Ring any bells?

I’m talking, of course of the Reagan administration’s response to HIV/AIDS in the early 1980s.

So lets not get complacent here: some of the same forces that let such things happen are still at work in all our societies.

(Perhaps the most disgusting response to AIDS came from the French, though, who let people die for reasons of state prestige.)

20

The Shamrockshire Eagle, editor and sole proprietor of 12.18.03 at 9:51 am

I’ve written a bit about this elsewhere —

Famine

— so now an attempt to expand on that and comment on some views expressed here. I’ve just made some points as they occur to me, so apologies it what’s below is a bit disconnected.

In the first year of the hunger, the British overnment, more specifically the responsible minister, Russell (? I think), did belatedly attempt to buy some quantities of Indian corn on the American market, only to find that the French and various German governments, among others, had already bought up the surplus to feed their hungry poor. Since Ireland had no government, her hungry poor went unfed. Russell’s bumbling was bad enough; but then came the change of ministry, and Trevelyan. The problem with him was, he used Ireland as an experimental subject on which to try out policies which would have been unthinkable in England — because *there*, he was answerable for his actions. He did not have it in his head to starve the people. He merely thought he’d leave laissez faire to do what it could.

It is however true to say that the focus of British policy in Ireland was to control the *effects* of what was even then regarded as a “natural disaster”, to alleviate the symptoms rather than cure the disease, and above all prevent the effects of the disease from spreading to “the mainland” . Thus, shipping off the afflicted to the new world, doling out enough soup to keep the poor from literally starving to death (the mass of unburied corpses would have created a serious public health problem is a country already ravaged by various types of “famine fever”) — and all the while exporting food from a country whose inhabitants could not pay for it. For food prices had (of course) soared. Even some of the well-off peasantry found it impossible to buy eatables, and these formed a goodly part of the later waves of emigration.

Even if prices had been stable, the lack of a developed money economy in Ireland — one consequence, among other things, of decades of forcing down the living standards of the peasantry — meant that once the staple crop failed, there was no alternative to mass charity. It wasn’t only that the poor had no money — though what money there was generally had to be used to pay the rent, — but also that there was often nothing to buy. The lack of a means of distribution may have been as big a factor as the price of the food.

Why did the people starve? In essence, because the economy was under-developed. Why was the economy under-developed? Because it was distorted by the connection with Britain. Not only foodstuffs, but capital was exported from the country — indeed, extorted, as Marx describes. I don’t know that Marx writes about the Famine per se anywhere, but what he says on Ireland *after* the Famine is germane, and well worth reading:


Ireland After the Famine

Remember, the social conditions that led to the Famine continued for several decades after it, and there were several famine scares during that period. Perhaps only the continued decline of the population through emigration averted another “clearance”.

The whole affair in retrospect has a sense of inevitability about it, the logical end result of decades, indeed centuries, of British policy in Ireland. To consider simply the policies of Russel and Trevelyan in isolation is to miss this wider meaning.

I’m not sure, by the way, that we can speak of Stalin’s *decision* to cause famine in Ukraine, any more than we can speak of Trevelyan’s decision to let famine be in Ireland. But actions speak louder than words. It is the results of policy that matter, regardless of subjective intention. Both famines took place, both famines were due to state policy; whether or no it was the intention of individuals within those states to cause what they in fact made happen is surely secondary.

The Great Famine is proof beyond doubt, for all those with eyes in their head, that the connection with Britain was (and, I would say, still is) disastrous for Ireland. Whether it can be called genocide is a moot point. Certainly, the effect was genocidal: the extirpation of the remnants of Gaelic Ireland. If this was not deliberate British policy, it certainly served such policy remarkably well.

And, finally, it’s somewhat typical of the weblog world that Derbyshire’s lightweight article is regarded as a serious account of the Famine. Ms Solent would have done better to visit her local library and borrow Woodham-Smith’s “The Great Hunger”. But then, that presumes that she really wants to learn and not simply to have her prejudices confirmed.

21

Dan Hardie 12.18.03 at 12:28 pm

Now that there are comments here by Sean Dunne of the Shamrockshire Eagle, and by Zizka linking to Dunne’s site, can I point out that this person holds contemptible views on World War 2? …

[LOTS OF STUFF DELETED BY CHRIS AS MODERATOR]

CB: No you can’t. Not because I hold any brief for Dunne on the various issues you raise but because this was a post on the Irish famine and more generally on the causes of public policy failures in times of crisis and the fact that you don’t like a commenter’s views on unrelated issues is beside the point. (Not that I can’t think of exceptions). If you wan’t to have a more general crack at Dunne then start your own blog and do it there. (This is a ruling and not an invitation for meta-discussion of appropriate comments on this thread).

22

Ryan 12.18.03 at 2:48 pm

zizka: Of course any good freemarketer must praise famines, which are a good way of reducing the costly burden of excess labor capacity.

Is it too late to qualify for the 2003 Straw Man Awards?

Derbyshire didn’t have the guts to say so, though.

If you honestly consider Derbyshire a “freemarketer”, read this. If you think the distinction is trivial because they’re all just “moronic brownshirt ****s”, I can’t help you.

dsquared: I note in passing that the UK of the 1840s had a lower ratio of tax to GDP, lower tariffs and far fewer regulations than the United States. It was much, much more comparable to a laissez-faire state than the modern USA.

Are we talking about the UK, or are we talking about an oppressed territory OF the UK whose citizens were not afforded the rights of UK citizens?

Chris Bertram: Since I didn’t mention the US in my post and Sen is not discussing the US in the passages mentioned, I’m inclined to diagnose this comment as an acute case of Carly Simon syndrome.

The relevant language in your post was, “Blaming the victim, bad choices, poor diet — I’ve heard those explanations before somewhere.”

It seemed me that you were referring to the two recent threads on Sen, in which you referred to American capitalism as “manifestly defective”, and commenters questioned how Sen differentiated between the health effects of genuine poverty (which clearly exists in the US) and the effects of bad choices in diet (which also exist in the US).

23

Chris Bertram 12.18.03 at 2:55 pm

Fair point, Ryan, though I intended the barb to be directed at people who jump at “blame the victim” explanations rather than to say anything substantive about the US. Sen, btw, thinks European capitalism is manifestly defective in providing people with employment opportunities – so there’s no general Europe v. US agenda lurking there.

24

Dan Hardie 12.18.03 at 3:24 pm

On the subject of famines, can I recommend Alex De Waal’s ‘Famine Crimes’? An excellent, contentious book, which devotes much of its first chapter to a discussion of Sen.

One of De Waal’s theses is that Sen’s refutation of the Malthus/Senior explanation of famine (which Sen mischievously labels ‘FAD’ or ‘Food Aggregate Deficit’) was in fact anticipated in all essentials by the British Raj’s Famine Codes instituted in India (from, I think, 1861 onwards). It seems reasonable to assume that the recent Mutiny had had a lot to do this; perhaps also the change in governing institution, from the East India Company to the Indian Civil Service.

And he further points out that the Famine Codes were anticipated in all their essentials by at least one surviving manual of government from pre-Raj India. A very interesting point, with a lot of implications: one of which is that British administrators in India, some of whom would have done Political Economy as part of their Greats courses, could in fact use their understanding of classical economics to evolve an analysis of famine that went strongly against Malthusian orthodoxy. Furthermore, their policy response combined price controls, anti-profiteering measures, public works, welfare and other extensive interventions in the workings of the market. It would be interesting to know how much impact this had on economics as it was taught back in British universities.

It’s also worth noting that the motive force behind Parnell’s Land League was fury at the famine, and fear in the early 1860s that there would be another famine- hence the Land League slogan ‘Never Again’, and hence the British agrarian reforms of the 1860s. Again, when faced by effective political pressure, British Imperial administrators became pragmatic interventionists pretty damn quickly.

[CB as moderator: deleted a final paragraph which constituted a further attempt IMHO to provoke an irrelevant flame-war with another commenter. Like I said — if you want to do this, rent your own bandwidth]

25

Ophelia Benson 12.18.03 at 3:35 pm

“It seems reasonable to assume that the recent Mutiny had had a lot to do this; perhaps also the change in governing institution, from the East India Company to the Indian Civil Service.”

Of course the two were closely linked – could in fact be regarded as two branches of the same thing: Mutiny-inspired reform (or at any rate change).

26

roger 12.18.03 at 3:42 pm

Dan Hardie’s comments provide a lot of food for thought — unfortunate as that cliche is in this context. Sen’s thesis, I think, is that famine is a crisis moment within the larger development of a particular set of policies. In India, and in Ireland, those policies had to do with land tenure, taxation, and the British desire to tear down barriers to the exchangability of land property and goods. It was, in fact, the desire — in accordance with the latter principle — to monetize the economy, in India, that lead to making taxes payable in specie. This tore at the heart of the traditional system, in which taxes were paid in-kind. In order to have the money to pay the taxes, the peasantry were forced to borrow it, at exorbitant interests, from a class of lenders that the British encouraged. This, in turn, destroyed the incentive to stock reserves of grain — which, of course, was the point. Eventually, the point was to make it possible to transfer property for money. In effect, the British administration was trying to transfer the Agricultural revolution of the eighteenth century in the West, which did monetize property, to India.
Personally, I think this point is fascinating. Since Hayek’s influential book, The Road to Serfdom, central planning has come to be defined exclusively in terms of the positive regulations implemented by the state concerning the production and tranfer of goods and services. This, of course, ignores the historic fact of central planning as a series of changes in a society wrought by changes in the legal structure of that society (which is, by the way, going on in Iraq). That the laissez faire utilitarians that created and implanted a legal code for India (from Macaulay to James Fitzjames Stephen) were engaged in central planning is a paradox only because of the way in which we’ve arbitrarily narrowed the semantic reach of the term.

Was the same thing going on in Ireland? That’s a good question.

27

Conrad Barwa 12.18.03 at 3:53 pm

One of De Waal’s theses is that Sen’s refutation of the Malthus/Senior explanation of famine (which Sen mischievously labels ‘FAD’ or ‘Food Aggregate Deficit’) was in fact anticipated in all essentials by the British Raj’s Famine Codes instituted in India (from, I think, 1861 onwards). It seems reasonable to assume that the recent Mutiny had had a lot to do this; perhaps also the change in governing institution, from the East India Company to the Indian Civil Service.

The Indian Famine Codes became operative in their complete form during the 1880s and they formed the bedrock of colonial policy; one could say it was the Deccan famines of the preceding decades that gave the push here. The famine issue is a complicated one which has generated a lot of debate so I won’t go into the details here; one should note however, that within the ICS itself there was a lot of debate over the correct response to it and many of the more junior field officers; were in favour of intervention as were their Presidency superiors but were frequently overruled by their seniors in the capital or the Indian Office. Like so much else regarding colonial policy at the time; fiscal conservatism was quite important in being the deciding factor. But the debate did occur and as with later pillars of British rule, like the martial race policy in recruitment, the supposed orthodoxy was actually a fairly recent and contested outcome. The British were well aware of the existing counter-cyclical responses taken by pre-colonial govts to deal with food shortages as a way of reacting to climactic variations in available food surpluses.

This of course, still doesn’t meant that mistakes could not occur; as the disastrous Bengal Famine of 1943 shows; much of Sen’s most brilliant work was demonstrating the falsity of the FAD thesis and the role of the state in exacerbating poor harvests by inappropriate purchasing policies. This famine which led to an estmiated 3 million deaths, was also one of the main reasons motivating Sen to undertake the work he did; as he was a young child when it occurred in his native Bengal.

“It seems reasonable to assume that the recent Mutiny had had a lot to do this; perhaps also the change in governing institution, from the East India Company to the Indian Civil Service.”

Of course the two were closely linked – could in fact be regarded as two branches of the same thing: Mutiny-inspired reform (or at any rate change).

No the timing is wrong for this. Also the ICS was very much in the early days simply adapted from the existing bureacracy of the EIC, the 1860s would have been too early for such a drastic change to occur. For a more in depth look at the debate prevailing in this period I recommend Sanjay Sharma’s “Famine, Philanthropy and the Colonial State: North India in the Early 19th Century” which covers the issue from this angle very well.

28

Mrs Tilton 12.18.03 at 4:01 pm

Ryan asks,

Are we talking about the UK, or are we talking about an oppressed territory OF the UK whose citizens were not afforded the rights of UK citizens?

No, we’re talking about the UK. At the time of the famine, Ireland was one of its constituent countries. The Irish were UK citizens afforded the same rights as other UK citizens. The penal laws that disabled Roman Catholic Irishmen disabled Roman Catholic Englishmen as well (and, I might add, at times also disabled some protestant Irishmen as well, though to a far smaller degree).

Through a mixture of neglect, malevolence and stupidity, the government of the day turned what should have been a serious but containable agricultural problem into a social and moral catastrophe. The history of English mismanagement of the famine is quite grim enough. There is no need to descend into inaccurate 800-years-of-Saxon-oppression rhetoric in describing it.

29

Zizka 12.18.03 at 4:05 pm

People should go to Brad DeLong, who says somewhat what I said, though he’s a far less horrible person than I am. DeLong is an economist but obviously not a pure freemarketer.

DeLong:”First, this is an example of a market economy working as designed. A market economy is (under proper assumptions about information, decreasing returns to scale, competition, et cetera) a mechanism for maximizing a weighted sum of individuals’ utilities. What your weight is depends on your wealth: the richer you are, the higher is the weight the market gives you in its utilitarian calculus. If your wealth is zero–which it is if you’re an Irish tenant farmer during the potato blight–then your weight is zero, and so the market blithely ships “wheat, oats, cattle, pigs, eggs and butter” down the Shannon to Merrie England.”

DeLong link

I’m looking forward to reading Sen’s book. The little snatches I read about the utility function make me eager for more. The utility function seems to be the link (or barrier) between economics narrowly defined and more comprehensive ways of defining the human good.

30

Zizka 12.18.03 at 4:14 pm

So the Irish died because they were Catholic, and not because they were Irish. Even though some Protestant Irishmen were also harmed. Because after all, Catholic Englishmen suffered too.

Well. That puts a whole different complexion on the matter.

31

dsquared 12.18.03 at 5:07 pm

I must confess to being unsure about quite how it would have helped to have given the Irish Catholic peasntry the right to buy land, since they didn’t have enough money to buy food.

32

Mrs Tilton 12.18.03 at 5:11 pm

No, Zizka; the Irish died because their sole staple crop failed and they hadn’t the means to buy alternative food. So they starved or, more usually, died of diseases they couldn’t fight off in their weakened state.

The famine didn’t particularly care about their religious denomination. RCs being both the majority of the population (esp. in the hardest-hit regions of the west and southwest) and the majority of the poor, they died in much heavier numbers. But protestants died as well. John Barkley, once moderator of the Irish presbyterian church, described his grandfather, who survived a famine childhood, as an old man who’d pick up any stray potato he found at the edge of a field and take it home in his pocket, because you never know.

The religion of the victims is neither here nor there. You are confusing the famine and the penal laws. The famine came nearly a half century after the Act of Union that made Ireland part of the UK. At that time UK law imposed disabilities on RCs without regard to whether they were Irish or English. Nearly all of these laws were gone shortly thereafter; the last major disability was the ineligibility of RCs to parliament (catholics had got the vote itself years earlier). And that disability was removed in 1829.

UK governance in the first half of the 19th c. was certainly ghastly by today’s standards. But Ryan simply has his facts wrong in suggesting that Ireland was at the time an ‘oppressed territory of the UK’ whose residents were ‘not afforded the rights of UK citizens’. Ireland was part of the UK and the Irish were citizens with the same rights as all other Britons (as the Irish then were); the legal disabilities abridging those rights for some citizens did so on the basis of their religion, not on the basis of their nationality.

All catholics in the UK suffered from legal discrimination, whatever their nationality. All of Ireland suffered in the famine, and poor prods were as prone to death as poor catholics; I don’t think RC Englishmen were much affected. Not a different complexion on the matter; these were two different matters altogether.

33

Mrs Tilton 12.18.03 at 5:15 pm

Dsquared,

oh, I think one need not have resorted to any such radical measure as letting the peasants buy land. Simply letting them (rather than the landowner) capture the benefit of improvements to their holdings might have done a measure of good. Indeed, perhaps they’d then have had some money by the time the famine came about.

34

Chris Bertram 12.18.03 at 5:22 pm

_Ireland was part of the UK and the Irish were citizens with the same rights as all other Britons_

But not the same rights, crucially (at least if Sen’s account is right on this point as I’m sure it is) with respect to Poor Relief.

35

Dan Hardie 12.18.03 at 5:42 pm

Conrad: thanks for the reference. You’re definitely right that the development of the Famine Codes took a lot of time and argument.

Roger: ‘Sen’s thesis, I think, is that famine is a crisis moment within the larger development of a particular set of policies.’ He does put a lot of stress on seeing famines in context, and certainly one of the contexts he makes a lot of (in ‘Hunger and Public Action’ and elsewhere) is the transition between an agrarian, largely pre-monetised economy (with paternalist, village or family-based welfare) to a monetised economy (with a food market and probably some form of free-ish press and responsive state). It’s the in-between phase which he sees as dangerous. But he notes that famines can occur in other contexts too. The key thing with him is the ‘entitlement’ idea: what causal nexus has led to a particular group of people losing their entitlement to food? Different famines, different chains of causation, although certain patterns do become depressingly familiar.

[CB as moderator: more stuff deleted — this is getting tiresome. Like I said, if you want to pick a fight with someone on a side issue, get your own blog. And, no, I’m not prepared to debate the merits of my policy here I’ve got better uses for my time.]

36

dsquared 12.18.03 at 6:55 pm

Mrs T: yes I see what you mean. Though I think I’m making the same point as Chris here; the discriminations made which could be said to have caused the famine were not ones which a movement in the direction of laissez-faire would have got rid of.

37

roger 12.18.03 at 9:17 pm

Dan, I understand that that there are other kinds of famines beside terror famines — as you point out: “The key thing with {Sen] is the ‘entitlement’ idea: what causal nexus has led to a particular group of people losing their entitlement to food?” But I think there is, in the cases of Ireland, India, and, I’d say, the Soviet Union and the famine in Mao’s China in the late fifties, another question: of what use is a famine? It can be punitive — certainly that was Churchill’s attitude towards the Bengal famine in the forties, and Stalin’s towards the Ukraine. My own sense is that, be the regime Marxist or laissez faire, the use value of the famine is to enforce and speed up the transformation of the agricultural economy in the direction of greater consolidation (although what was happening under Mao is a huge puzzle that might defy that paradigm). In other words, beyond the ideological differences between socialist and capitalist regimes, both developed by liquidating the peasant economies that preceded them. Could that consolidation be achieved without sacrificing 10 million people here, 1 million there? That’s a good question. We know that, in India, the Indian Civil Service actually did stop famines before the great famine of 1876 — and we know the officials responsible were PUNISHED for it. It was considered too much money spent, and for what? Saving Indian lives — not a priority for such as Lord Lytton, and some of his successors. Lytton, in particular, was proud of saving the government money during the Deccan famines of the seventies — and that, upon touring the labor camps where thousands died, he complained that they were doling out too much food (as he said, the labor camps were like a picnic). While this might simply be madness, there’s a sense in which this madness was in conformity with the Raj’s policy.
By the by — I don’t understand how monetising the agricultural economy also necessitates “some form of free-ish press and responsive state” — there doesn’t seem to be any logical connection here.

38

Vinteuil 12.19.03 at 3:48 am

Derbyshire:

“What a dreadful human calamity might have been averted if the U.S. authorities had had the wit to ban the export of infected potatoes! Why did they not do this? In part, for the same reason that the British government did not organize adequate relief, or prevent the export of foodstuffs from Ireland while Irish people were starving: it was not within the nature, philosophy or resources of Anglo-Saxon governments to do such things in the 1840s.”

Sen: “…by the 1840s, when the Irish famine occurred, an extensive system of poverty relief was fairly well established in Britain, as far as Britain itself was concerned…”

Whether there is a contradiction between these two passages depends on how one interprets Derbyshire’s phrase “such things.”

This is a very weak example of Derbyshire’s “awful”-ness, and an even weaker example of the sort of “misinformation” that gets “circulated” around the “blogosphere.”

I found the piece quite interesting and Chris Bertram’s attack on it excessive.

39

TW 12.19.03 at 4:31 am

Whether there is a contradiction between these two passages depends on how one interprets Derbyshire’s phrase “such things.”

Also the phrase “adequate relief” as opposed to “extensive system of poverty relief.” Something can be “extensive” for some (English) without being “adequate” for others (Irish).

This is a very weak example of Derbyshire’s “awful”-ness, and an even weaker example of the sort of “misinformation” that gets “circulated” around the “blogosphere.”

I concur, a disagreement (including of interpretation or emphasis) between two people does not necessarily mean misinformation on either’s part. Look at how many different takes we have on the causes of the Great Depression or the War Between the States which agree on some key points but may differ on others. The fact that people may disagree or characterize some points differently does not necessarily mean that someone is being dishonest.

40

dsquared 12.19.03 at 7:35 am

You are both surely wrong. Derbyshire’s entire point rests on the unsupported (and false) assertion that the British state was not in the business of large-scale provision of food to the hungry. If he’d troubled to look this up in a decent textbook he’d have found it was wrong. He therefore either didn’t bother to do so or ignored it. Chris’s very mild claims are entirely appropriate.

41

Dan Hardie 12.19.03 at 1:09 pm

Roger:

‘By the by — I don’t understand how monetising the agricultural economy also necessitates “some form of free-ish press and responsive state” — there doesn’t seem to be any logical connection here.’

Sorry for giving a very weak abbreviated summary of some of Sen’s work. There’s no way in which monetizing an agricultural economy necessitates a freer press and a democratised state, but the one has often followed the other- and Sen has seen the one without the other as particularly prone to famine. Sen speaks of freedom of information, and some sort of polity where public pressure would force the state to act against hunger, as some of the main weapons against famine in a monetised economy: if families or communities can’t cope themselves (eg no savings to buy food, or they’re priced out of the market), the State needs to be pressured into keeping them alive. The willingness of some British Raj officials to see Indians starve to death in the late 19th Century (and the way in which they were eventually out-argued, at least partly because the British were worried about feeding Indian rebellion) fits right in to Sen’s framework.

Re the ‘uses’ of famine being a different question to those raised by Sen’s entitlement work: no, I think that ‘useful’ (if you like, politically instrumental) famines are pretty well covered in Sen’s work, and certainly don’t entail any rethinking of- still less refute- the ‘entitlements’ approach. I think that the entitlement theory was an attempt (and a successful one) to answer the question ‘what is common to all famines, whatever their cause?’ And the answer Sen came up with was- people lose an entitlement to enough food to keep them alive.

If at first this seems to cover a multitude of possible explanations, that is the point of it: Sen wanted to get away from a priori assumptions that this, that or the other factor was the sole or overriding cause of every famine (‘The State destroyed the food market’; ‘The food market led to profiteering and the State did nothing’; ‘There wasn’t enough food’.) The entitlements approach rules out one-size-fits-all dogmatism, which is one of its great strengths.

David Keen’s book ‘The Uses of Famine’, which did rather suggest that Sen hadn’t noticed that famines could be either deliberately started or, once started, used by political groups, seems to me very weak indeed in arguing this point. In fact Keen doesn’t really argue, just repeatedly invoke Foucault. His book is a good field study of a particular famine in the Sudan, and its beneficiaries, but the theoretical side is not worth bothering with. Sen seems to me well aware that famines have political causes, contexts and (sometimes) beneficiaries.

A question for philosophers, even minor ones like Bertram: in which possible worlds is the Third Reich irrelevant to famine? Presumably those in which the Third Reich either didn’t exist, or did exist but didn’t instigate or benefit from famine. Not, alas, this world…

[CB — even a philosopher as minor as I undoubtely am is able to detect that the final paragraph of this post is intended as a provocation.]

42

Vinteuil 12.19.03 at 4:18 pm

dsquared: it is possible that Derbyshire meant “such things” to include “large-scale provision of food to the hungry.” But it is also possible that he meant something closer to what he actually wrote–i.e., that “it was not within the nature, philosophy or resources of Anglo-Saxon governments” to put themselves out much “while Irish people were starving.”

Whichever way you take it, this is hardly his “entire point,” or even his main point in the passage in question, which concerns the failure of the U.S. to impose an agricultural quarantine.

Derbyshire comes closer to saying what Chris Bertram wants him to say earlier in the article:

“There is no doubt…that the British governing classes of the 1840s included many [heartless] men…and their heartlessness is the main indictment against them. It had a number of sources. One was plain despair. For years before the famine it was perfectly obvious that Ireland was heading for a demographic catastrophe. Everybody knew this, and many said so…. From 1801 to 1841, the Catholic population of southern Ireland quintupled. A thing like that is hard not to notice. And yet, within the political thinking of the time, nobody, not even the best-intentioned and most charitable observers, could think of anything to do to avert the coming disaster. Britain was a minimum-government state, ill-equipped for the sort of speedy, wide-scale relief the situation called for.”

But even this is arguably consistent with Sen’s account. The English could well have a “system of poverty relief” that was “fairly well established in Britain” while still being “ill-equipped,” materially and ideologically, to deal with the massive emergency in Ireland.

Derbyshire goes on to emphasize the ideological point: “Economic ideas, too, contributed to the general callousness of the authorities. This was especially true after the Tory administration of Robert Peel, which actually did attempt some substantial public relief, gave way to Lord John Russell’s Whig government in 1846. Lord Russell held to a very pure version of laissez-faire economics, which tolerated as little government interference as possible.”

Maybe it’s just me, but I just don’t think that in this particular article Derbyshire comes across as some sort of extreme right wing moral monster. In fact, I would expect the Crooked Timber folks wholeheartedly to agree with his conclusion:

“To say that governments were not equipped for these tasks does not, of course, absolve them of moral responsibility. Twenty-two centuries before the famine, the Chinese philosopher Mencius wondered rhetorically: “What should we think of a ruler who allows his people to starve?” What then should we think of Robert Peel, Lord Russell, and their administrators? These men were responsible for the citizens of the United Kingdom, which at that time included Ireland. They were responsible to provide for their defense in case of invasion, and for their relief in case of natural disasters — the most elementary functions of government. They failed in that responsibility. They — and, to a lesser degree, the authorities of New York and the United States — must forever bear the stain of the famine.”

43

Vinteuil 12.19.03 at 4:24 pm

Oh, and by the way–to see modern Americans of the lower classes who suffer from obesity because of too much junk food as “victims” in anything like the same sense that the Irish of 1848 were victims of the potato famine is the sort of thing that gives today’s left a bad name.

44

Thorley Winston 12.19.03 at 4:43 pm

Daniel Davies wrote:

You are both surely wrong. Derbyshire’s entire point rests on the unsupported (and false) assertion that the British state was not in the business of large-scale provision of food to the hungry.

That is only one of many possible interpretations but it is not what he actually said:

“What a dreadful human calamity might have been averted if the U.S. authorities had had the wit to ban the export of infected potatoes! Why did they not do this? In part, for the same reason that the British government did not organize adequate relief, or prevent the export of foodstuffs from Ireland while Irish people were starving: it was not within the nature, philosophy or resources of Anglo-Saxon governments to do such things in the 1840s.”

There is nothing in this excerpt from Derb’s article saying that the British government did not have any sort of relief for its own citizens, but merely that it did not “organize adequate relief, or prevent the export of foodstuffs from Ireland while Irish people were starving” and that it “was not within the nature, philosophy or resources of Anglo-Saxon governments to do such things in the 1840s.”

It could just as easily mean that the British government’s nature was not to help out the Irish hungry even though it provided some relief for its own hungry people (which seems consistent with Sen’s excerpt).

Or it could mean that while they had some programs (e.g. Poor Laws) they were not adequate to deal with the problem in Ireland because they were more localized or on a smaller scale (as were the ones in the United States which predated the New Deal).

It does not follow though that Derb’s categorically stated that there was not any form of governmental relief even though in terms of philosophy and resources, they were most certainly more limited than what we have today.

The assertion that Chris and Daniel attribute to Derb’s point is merely their interpretation of what he could have meant rather than what he actually wrote. If someone wants to accuse him of making up stuff as was the charge, then it might help to actually find something more concrete and less vague to critique.

45

Chris Bertram 12.19.03 at 4:47 pm

Vinteuil: your last remark only makes sense if you believe that someone has made the assertion you suggest. But no-one has.

46

Chris Bertram 12.19.03 at 4:58 pm

Thorley,

I’m wondering which school of textual interpretation you belong to. Since you’re of conservative views and refer to the author of the text in questions as “Derb” I’m guessing Straussian….

47

Thorley Winston 12.19.03 at 5:32 pm

Bert wrote:

I’m wondering which school of textual interpretation you belong to.

The one where you actually read what a person writes rather than trying to set up a strawman argument so you can claim that based on your interpretation of what he might have meant, that he is just “making it up as he goes along.”

It was also incidentally the same school that taught me that when you wish to compare different groups to test a hypothesis such as why one group’s life expectancy is shorter than the other, you try to find two groups as similar to each other in other respects as possible and hold all other variables constant.

48

Vinteuil 12.19.03 at 5:49 pm

Chris Bertram: you ended your original post with these words: “Blaming the victim, bad choices, poor diet — I’ve heard those explanations before somewhere.” And then Ted Barlow tittered in sympathy.

I was assuming that you were drawing a parallel between Edward Trevelyan’s rhetoric and that of the conservatives who commented on your first post on Sen’s book a few days ago. But when those conservatives talk about bad choices with respect to poor diet, they are thinking precisely of the epidemic of obesity, with all it’s attendant health problems, that notoriously afflicts America’s lower classes. In that context, your parallel makes no sense unless you see junk-food addicts as victims.

But perhaps you didn’t realize what the conservatives on that thread were talking about–which might actually make the indignation with which you greeted their remarks more comprehensible to me.

Incidentally, I have had several discussions lately with people on the left who *do* see Big Macs, potato chips, and Coca Cola as forms of victimization. If you and Ted Barlow do not think that way, then I am relieved to hear it, and sorry that I mistook your meaning.

49

Vinteuil 12.19.03 at 5:55 pm

Chris Bertram again: re “Derb” and “Straussian”…are you under the impression that John Derbyshire is a “neo-conservative?” Or just people who call him by his nickname? Either way–bizarre.

[CB: no. The nickname suggested to me a certain affection, but the real point I was somewhat sarcastically making concerned the notoriously inventiveness of Straussians when it comes to reading texts. I’m sorry you didn’t get it.]

50

Matt Weiner 12.19.03 at 6:01 pm

Textual note:
Derbyshire wrote, “In part, for the same reason that the British government did not organize adequate relief, or prevent the export of foodstuffs from Ireland while Irish people were starving.”

If this sentence is grammatical, “while Irish people were starving” modifies “prevent the export of foodstuffs…” and not “organize adequate relief.” In order to make it modify “organize adequate relief” Derbyshire would have to eliminate the comma before “or” (or perhaps insert a comma after “Ireland”).

So Chris Bertram and Daniel Davies appear to be right that Derbyshire seems to spread misinformation about the British government’s ability to do poor relief at the time.

As for the question of whether Derbyshire is vile, I think that can be settled without reference to this article.

51

Chris Bertram 12.19.03 at 6:12 pm

There is indeed a parallel between Trevelyan’s attitude and that of those modern conservatives to whom you refer in that they both attribute the excess mortality of the populations concerned to the bad dietary choices of those very populations.

But it doesn’t follow from the fact that I see a parallel between their attitudes that I also see a parallel your suggest I see between the two populations. For that to be the case I would have to endorse, at least in large part, the explanations proferred by Trevelyan and the conservatives to whom you refer for that excess mortality. And plainly I do neither of those things.

Not that there aren’t parallel’s to be drawn. In particular, wherever policy-makers feel a sense of cultural alienation from and perhaps hostility towards the most vulnerable and incline to blame them for their misfortune, less will be done to address the real (rather than made up by people like those conservatives) causes of that misfortune. (A case in point being the Reaganite indifference towards AIDS victims in the early 1980s).

52

Vinteuil 12.19.03 at 6:16 pm

Matt Weiner: you cannot possibly believe that the phrase “organize adequate relief” is not intended to refer to Ireland during the famine.

53

Matt Weiner 12.19.03 at 7:07 pm

Vinteuil–
Hm, this is subtler than I thought. The passage strikes me as saying “Anglo-Saxon societies did not prevent the export of foodstuff while the natives were starving, nor organize adequate relief,” but now I think that this turns on the reference of “such things.”

I think Bertram and Davies are still dead right in the context of Derbyshire’s essay. Derbyshire says,
“Britain was a minimum-government state, ill-equipped for the sort of speedy, wide-scale relief the situation called for,”
which doesn’t account for the Poor Laws. And since Derbyshire claims, seemingly on the basis of Malthus, that “For years before the famine it was perfectly obvious that Ireland was heading for a demographic catastrophe,” it won’t do to say that Britain wasn’t in a position to do a lot of famine relief at once–by Derbyshire’s lights, they didn’t need to.

I mean, yoicks, he fulminates about the idea that the Irish famine was deliberate (on the part of the UK), and then quotes Lord Cardigan saying that the million who died were “not enough to do any good.” Cognitive dissonance, anyone?

54

Vinteuil 12.19.03 at 7:10 pm

Chris Bertram: actually, I think that poor diet came in third behind high rates of homicide and HIV infection in those conservative explanations for excess African American mortality.

I am a little surprised to learn that you do not accept those explanations *even in part*. I had assumed your position was that, while these white/black differences are real, they should be seen not as a product of “choice,” but of past and present victimization–slavery, Jim Crow, ongoing discrimination, etc. Which would bring us back to the idea that when American blacks die at disproportionate rates from, among other things, heart disease and stroke brought on in part by poor diet, they, like the Irish in the potato famine, should be seen as victims.

If you do *not* think that African Americans suffer from higher rates of homicide, HIV infection, heart disease, stroke, etc., and that thiese factors do not largely account for their higher mortality rate, than I guess I just don’t know what to say.

As for “the Reaganite indifference toward AIDS victims in the early 1980s”…well, I have probably already annoyed you quite enough for one day.

55

Vinteuil 12.19.03 at 7:33 pm

Matt Weiner: do you take the position that the famine was a deliberate act of British policy? Judging by the passage that Chris Bertram quotes, Sen seems to attribute it more to callous indifference arising from cultural alienation, which seems consistent with Derbyshire’s view.

By the way, I once exchanged a few e-mails with Derbyshire, and found him rather gratuitously nasty, so I am perfectly prepared to believe that he’s awful. I just don’t think I’d base that judgment on this particular piece.

56

Chris Bertram 12.19.03 at 7:44 pm

I didn’t say that I don’t accept _those_ explanations (the ones you just listed) “even in part.” I said that for what you stated of me to be true I’d have to endorse “in large part” the explanations _I_ was referring to — by which I meant in context the “bad diet” explanations. (I can see how you might have misread me as referring to the wider list of explanations.)

I can certainly accept that all of those factors figure _somewhere_ in the story which tells us why African Americans have such low life expectancy. I rather doubt that the dietary aspect accounts for much of the difference between African Americans and the wider US population.

57

Matt Weiner 12.19.03 at 8:10 pm

do you take the position that the famine was a deliberate act of British policy?

No, but it looks as though the failure to provide relief may have been a deliberate act of policy, based in part on anti-Irish animus. Derbyshire certainly seems to be playing both down, implying that the failure was an accidental byproduct of laissez-faire and that the anti-Irish animus was born of despair or some such. I really don’t see Derbyshire acknowledging cultural alienation at all.

I’m not sure whether I would tag Derbyshire “awful” on the basis of this article alone–ill-informed, apparently. My judgment has to do with other writings–the anti-Chelsea Clinton screed for one.

58

Vinteuil 12.19.03 at 9:15 pm

Chris Bertram: fair enough. I agree that dietary factors are probably relatively unimportant. And it is much more plausible to present black homicide rates as a form of victimization. (Not necessarily right–just plausible.) Differential HIV infection rates are iffier–choice? victimization? I dunno. And I’ve been there. Lots of personal experience with that one–more’s the pity. Anyway, thanks for your interesting and patient responses.

P.S.: few neo-cons harbor much affection for John Derbyshire. I don’t know whether or not Thorley Winston is an exception to that rule, but I suppose *he* knows, and can speak for himself. You’re right, of course, about the “inventiveness of Straussians when it comes to reading texts.” Another thing I’ve experienced at first hand. Feh. I just don’t think it’s relevant here.

Matt Weiner: I haven’t seen the “anti-Chelsea Clinton screed”; it’s hard to imagine how anything that could reasonably be so described could fail to be awful. Same goes for hit-pieces on Dubbyah’s unfortunate offspring.

59

Matt Weiner 12.20.03 at 12:43 am

Derbyshire on Chelsea, if you want to check first-hand. The part at the end about punishment to the ninth degree tends to attract the most flak. Ted B. discusses it here.

60

Roger 12.20.03 at 2:17 am

The Malthusian explanation is not very plausible. The population of England experienced the same kind of exponential growth, especially in the eighteenth century, without famine. But during that same century, and on into the nineteenth, the English had done their best to decimate Irish industries (as they were also doing to the Indian textile industry), and drew away the capital that could be invested into agricultural improvement into English ventures. Angus Calder’s book, Revolutionary Empire, cites a whole literature of English military and government men mulling “removing” the Catholic Irish — in fact, the war against the North American Indians came out of the same mindset, and was often strategized by the same thinkers (Walter Raleigh, for instance), who floated schemes to make Ireland Irisch-rein. This is the long, tedious and disgusting background to the Victorian Irish policy.

Does this mean that famine in the 1840s was intended? No, but it does mean that there was a whole cultural bias against helping the Irish, and there were goals that could be met by weakening the Irish. That Irish protestants were caught in the net, too, isn’t really relevant. The great Anglo-Irish landholders of the Pale weren’t, and they certainly saw a point in evicting tenants and destroying the intricate net of customary tenants’ rights that bound them in their dealings with the peasantry.

61

Gri mReaoer 12.20.03 at 3:27 pm

I have just read the “awful” John Derbyshire’s article. It sems eminently fair to me. People have forgotten that, before contraception, married women typically produced a baby every two years. Famine and disease were the standard methods of population control. Throughout Europe, it was not unusual for large numbers to starve whenever the harvest was poor.

Comments on this entry are closed.